Relational Money
A talk given at the Economic Theory For The Anthropocene conference,
Tuesday 3rd – Wednesday 4th July 2018
University of Surrey, Guildford
By Prof. John Wood
"The quality of money consists exclusively in its quantity.” (Georg Simmel, 1900)
ABSTRACT
Money Shaped The Anthropocene
Today, money appears to be growing under its own momentum. This is a troubling situation, given its similarity with the last global financial crash in 2007-8. What is even more troubling is that most economic critics appear to focus on the social, rather than upon the ecological implications of our predicament. Admittedly, some economists have long been trying to persuade their colleagues that economic orthodoxy is out-of-sync with the global ecosystem (e.g. Douthwaite, 1993; Stern, 2006). This appears to have had little effect, as mainstream economists continue to promote policies that are part of the problem, rather than the solution. Even the Bank of England continues to subsidise the carbon energy industries in a bid to reduce financial risk (Macquarie, 2018). This is myopic and counterproductive. Humanity has crossed at least three of nine ‘planetary boundaries’ (Rockström, 2015) and we have now entered the era of the Anthropocene. If Homo sapiens is to avoid the very worst scenarios we must switch from the search for environmental 'sustainability' (Brundtland, 1987) and create economic policies that deliver ecological 'regeneration' (Wahl, 2016). We need radical change, but new paradigms tend to remain unthinkable until people learn to think in the language of the next one. This is exemplified by the majority of politicians, economists and journalists who refrain from challenging the clamour for limitless 'economic growth'. This is unfortunate as, in ecological terms, the term 'growth' (e.g. GDP) makes no distinction between those monetary transactions that are benign and others that are self-destructive (Jackson, 2009; Keen, 2017).
The Trickle-Up Effect
At the global scale, the factory-to-landfill economics of 'frictionless' consumption and thoughtless disposal is having a catastrophic effect on the biosphere. However, one of the main drivers of consumption has been a rapid growth in the financial credit market. The principle behind it is not new. One of the first futures markets (e.g. Code of Hammurabi 1750 BC), established a legal basis for delivering assets at a future date (Urch, 1929). This acted as a catalyst to human endeavour, because it could encourage new transactions in times of severe pessimism or scarcity. The principle of using 'future' money as an attractor to social regeneration is also implied in Adam Smith's 'invisible hand' thesis (Smith, 1776). Smith argued that, by actively encouraging local self-interest, the wealth accrued would inevitably 'trickle down' to the needy. Today, however, it is important to ask why money is trickling upward, rather than downward (Bregman, 2017). It would seem that increasing one's wealth has become easier than re-distributing it to others. Mansa Musa (c.1280–1337) is estimated to have been the richest person in history. However, in contrast with most of today's super-rich he stands out because of his altruism and promotion of learning. Currently, the richest fifty individuals own around $1.9 trillion - a quarter of the value of all the coins & banknotes in the world. However, few, if any, of these individuals appear to provide essential products, or services. Their social contribution includes 'one-click shopping', the automation of production and delivery systems and algorithms that persuade more citizens to buy more non-essential products. Of course, many in the rich-list gained their money simply by manipulating money (e.g. the notion that the pound could be shorted for personal gain via Brexit).
The Laundering of Value
For the most part, money is still issued by private banks, some of whom behave as financial predators (Ryan-Collins, Greenham, Werner & Jackson, 2011). As the management of monetisation process is extended throughout the whole system, with some exceptions, the creative potential of individuals becomes increasingly discouraged and dissipated because the majority are employed as minions who serve the growth of capital. Also, few of us appear to understand how money works. Although it looks simple, in some ways, it is bafflingly counterintuitive. For example, what does the legend on the banknote "I Promise to Pay The Bearer The Sum of Fifty Pounds" actually mean? If it behaves exactly as one might expect the sum of £50 to behave, where, exactly is "the sum" to which it refers? A recent poll (2017) showed that only 15% of MPs in the UK House of Commons were aware that new money is created when banks make loans (Baaquie, 2018). Politicians appear to be concerned about money laundering, yet its intrinsic inertness and forgetfulness makes it a perfect vehicle for erasing its spending history and context. Bizarrely, its semantic elusiveness acts as a powerful attractor to avarice and, thereby, economic growth. As Georg Simmel said, “regardless of the amount, the liveliness of attached hopes gives money a glow” (Simmel, 1900). In cognitive terms, although today's money has been reduced to a number in a digital database, humans love to visualise its infinite potential. Part of Simmel's analysis explains how the acquisition and fetishisation of money is, for many, an end in itself. This is not a hapless chance, but because of the way money was designed. As he noted, "the quality of money...consists exclusively in its quantity" (Simmel, 1900).
Synergy
All of the above arguments go some way to explain why the derivatives markets now dwarf all other monetary transaction. Currently, these transactions are too big to count as a reliable sum, but are estimated to run at somewhere between $544 trillion and $1.2 quadrillion. The top-heavy nature of capital is unlikely to improve while we continue to regard commodities (e.g. sacks of X, barrels of Y, or 'n' number of slaves), as discrete units. In the past, the circulation of commodity money was limited by the availability of the commodity itself, whether it consisted of salt, cattle, or gold. On the other hand, fiat money can be issued in virtually unlimited quantities. By regulating the quantity of money issued, central banks can retain some level of control over inflation levels. Today, however, many believe that money would be better generated at a local, grassroots level. Some of these pioneers are driven by altruistic visions of a more egalitarian, 'bottom-up' economy. However, others include a motley range of technocentrists, innovators and opportunists. Perhaps this would enable it to keep pace with the fluctuating fortunes of global ecological wellbeing being. Unfortunately, even at the relatively low levels of use, for example, Bitcoin is making huge energy demands. As its early adoptors need to create their new 'coins' at the lowest prices, this is serving to prolong the extraction and burning of some of the dirtiest non-renewable fuels.
Replacing Monetary Profit With Relational Opportunity
Ultimately, cryptocurrencies appear to be emulating the granular nature of fiat money. Although they are novel, in many respects, they work in a similar way to fiat currencies. A more sophisticated approach for the design of cryptocurrencies would be to focus on the auditing of relations, rather than things, as the cultivation of difference is an abundant source of synergies. (Full discussion of synergy is beyond the scope of this paper. C.f. Corning, 2003; Wood, 2012). However, although deriving synergy from the combining of existing ones is likely to be greener and cheaper than extracting new materials from the ground, the quantifiability of money makes it easier to use. This explains why businesses still seem to prefer the explicit logic of numerical profits, rather than learning to explore the often ineffable abundances that pertain to synergy. Whereas money was designed, literally, to 'add up', synergies are virtually countless. They emerge in mysterious forms and, therefore, operate outside the predictive order of mathematics. This implies that, in a greener, lower energy future, our most precious assets would be local synergies, rather than single products and cash crops. If so, money would be designed to encourage the cultivation of a diversities-of-diversities. This, in turn, would enable communities to harvest an ultimate 'synergies-of-synergies' (c.f. Fuller, 1975).
Our Monkey Brains
Perhaps currency designers can learn something from monkeys. Whereas human societies continue to use fiscal instruments as a form of social governance, our elder cousins prefer more direct, one-to-one methods. This does not necessarily mean they are less intelligent as, apparently, our chimpanzee cousins are smart enough to use fiat money (Chen, Lakshminarayanan & Santos, 2006). Perhaps unsurprisingly, they make cognitive errors that resemble the ones we make, albeit with less damaging environmental consequences. Some researchers observing the mutual grooming habits of Bonobo monkeys have identified them as a kind of currency exchange (Schroepfer-Walker, Wobber & Hare, 2015). However, this reflects a rather anthropocentric standpoint. Whereas monetary transactions are profoundly indirect and abstract, grooming looks to be much richer and rewarding. It is an important social lubricant, replete with hidden social and ecological synergies. This is because humans developed it to help them scale up their organisations beyond their cognitive limits, in evolutionary terms. Realistically, to make Blockchain systems work best we should consider reducing the scale of communities in order to obviate the need for a numbers-based bureaucracy. This is necessitated by our level of development, in evolutionary terms. Whereas our chimpanzee ancestors live in groups of up to 30 or so, modern humans are capable of maintaining effective convivial relationships in larger group sizes. According to anthropological studies, human individuals can sustain convivial relations with up to around 150 people (Dunbar, 1992).
Exchanging Responsibility With Accountability
Ten thousand years ago, the success of agricultural food production methods enabled the first farming communities to expand their numbers beyond their social comfort zones, which led to cruder and less direct modes of discourse. As organisations grow beyond the Dunbar number, the need to add additional layers of managers introduces barriers to communication within, and across, them. In top-down systems, when actions are stripped of their context, value is dissipated (c.f. Ashby, 1956). Before long, top-down rules and standards eclipse the local dialects of willingness. In short the cultures of responsibility gave way to systems of accountability. Five thousand years ago the first fiat currencies (unit-based monies) enabled emperors to assemble armies of unprecedented size; then to maintain power by managing the flow of money. (Graeber, 2012). Thus, it has proved to be an extraordinarily effective instrument for managing wars and empires, as it enabled rulers to account for numerous transactions over large distances and timescales. This illustrates Simmel's description of money as “…the purest example of the tool” (Simmel, 1900). However, as the scale of monetary circulations exceed the Dunbar limits, the greater will be the chance that investments will become, in effect, 'foreign investments'. This is because, as the number of unknown agents grows, proportionately, the money in circulation will become more dissipative and prone to 'external' exploitation or manipulation.
Four-Fold Thinking
In evolutionary terms, the invention of money was a very recent event. This is why, as humans, we all find it hard to overcome our innate cognitive biases (e.g. Kahneman & Tversky, 2013). Research suggests, for example, that we all tend to confuse 'quality' (e.g. product efficacy and longevity) with 'quantity' (e.g. price). It is well known that humans become confused by large or, even, moderately sized numbers (Du Sautoy, 2009). Perhaps we are even less literate, in numerical terms, than most of us would like to believe. In 1956, George Miller popularised the notion that the average person can conceptualise only between 5 and 9 interdependent things at the same time. In 2001, Nelson Cowan tested this hypothesis but concluded that our brains 'chunk' information in fours. Gobbet and Clarkson (2004) challenged Cowan's findings with evidence that many of us have to chunk information in twos, rather than fours. This was corroborated by Klingberg & Torkel, (2009) who showed that we may give the illusion of 'multi-tasking' by switching backwards and forwards between two 'paired' sets of tasks. Practically speaking, however, this paper argues that 4 is a realistic starting point for innovators, even if it might be ambitious. It is interesting that Buckminster Fuller anticipated these findings in 1949, when he suggested that the mind works in a tetrahedral (four-fold) way.
Distributed Ledgers
In England, from around 1100AD until the early 19th century, the majority of monetary transactions were recorded on tally sticks. These were hand-made ledgers fashioned out of hand-sized lengths of wood. The several parties would use them to carve notches as a record of the agreement. The number, size and angle of the notches denoted the requisite number of pounds, shillings and pence. Once completed, the stick would be split along its length to give two halves, each with an identical notch profile. Tally sticks have been compared with what, in the digital era, we now call 'distributed ledgers' (e.g. Cheesman, 2018). There is great excitement within the 'geeky' communities about the advent of a new golden age of 'smart' AI widgets that will save us all from the bother of being human. However, despite the apparent sophistication of our Post-Enlightenment species, Homo sapiens remains a rather somatic and haptic creature. Perhaps our 'four-fold' brains evolved to accommodate the tacit world of two arms and two legs. Whatever the explanation, our unique sensory nature should be accommodated when we design a better currency system. Tally Sticks offer certain benefits when compared with digital peer-to-peer systems. Where most Blockchain systems use remote algorithms to create authentic identities, the making of a tally stick record was a co-creative act made more memorable because of its embodied nature. This also made faking difficult, partly because of the wood's unique grain characteristics and partly because any subsequent tampering of one half would have shown up as a mismatch with the other, once the two halves were were put back together.
Summative Reasoning
It is worth noting that the vast complexity and potential of natural systems does not conform to the received logic of things. This is because the mathematics of money and accountancy is fundamentally summative. Perhaps we think in such a granular way because Homo sapiens has been mining and shaping minerals from the ground for around 3 million years. Many interpret Pythagoras's (570–495 BC) famous saying: "all things are number" as a belief that the world is, in essence, atomistic. Others read this as a reference to 'ratios', rather than to discrete integers. When inanimate things have to be shared out equally, ratios are a handy shorthand for apportioning them. Moreover, a mutual faith in numbers may help to build trust within a transaction. However, whereas, relations are multi-dimensional, ratios are one-dimensional entities. In monetary terms, for example, ‘unity’ can be regarded as a final sum of identical quantities (Simmel, 1900, p. 271). By contrast, the ‘unity’ maintained by living systems exists as an ongoing act of self-regulation that is qualitative (Maturana & Varela, 1992. p. 51).
Relational Thinking
There are several practical reasons why counting nouns became the basis for monetary thinking, rather than the evaluation of transactional relations. Unfortunately, the imperialistic grammar intrinsic to money was designed to standardise human relations. Using it can blind us to the more subtle opportunities and new values. We may forget, for example, that the 'things' we may find in a particular room will always be outnumbered by their interrelationships. Secondly, we may overlook the fact that relations cannot be represented adequately (c.f. Rayner, 2012) without mapping both their intrinsic component parts (c.f. Kvitash, 2003) and the relevant context (e.g. Sperber and Wilson, 1986) that helps to nourish and sustain them. By focusing exclusively on numbers, raw materials, or the ratios between them we are likely to invoke the 'Law of Decreasing Returns'. This is because, ultimately, value is generated only by managing complex relations. Most importantly, if we wish to benefit from the 'Law of Increasing Returns' it is vital to uphold an optimistic economy of team relations. This may mean relinquishing predictive certainty in favour of a more creative and combinatorial way of thinking. At least, it probably means losing count of the certainties, in the quest to harvest more opportunities. As the economist, Paul Romer said, “...possibilities do not add up. They multiply.” (Romer, 1991).
Towards A Relational Mathematics
A relational approach to money challenges the additive logic and imperialist grammar taught in schools. However, as most of us still inhabit this paradigm, such a departure may seem heretical, even self-contradictory. Relations are certainly more plentiful than their component parts, but they are also more useful (i.e. valuable). Each relationship may conceal unforeseen synergies, so 'accounting' for them may mean learning to think in manifold relations. The dividends that accrue can be evidenced when a given sum exceeds the 100% of its original ingredient parts. Unfortunately, relations can seldom be defined by the boundaries between disciplines, or categories. In other words, synergies do not respect customary distinctions, say, between animate and inanimate things. Hence, we can no longer usefully separate human agencies from each other. Nor can we separate these relational entities from the 'things' they choose to exchange. When we analyse the mathematical ratios that pertain among team members and the number of relationships among them we find, for example, that:
- In a team of 8, each team member is responsible for 25% of all relations
- In a team of 4, each team member is responsible for 50% of all relations
- In a team of 3, each team member is responsible for 66.6% of all relations
- In a team of 2, each team member is responsible for 100% of all relations
Euler's Intrinsic Profit
In the simplest terms, a synergy may consist of two existing 'assets' that become combined to create a new, additional asset. The more ingredients we use, the more possible synergies we may find. For example, if we combine three assets we get the same number of synergies as the assets we started with. (i.e. 3 ingredients gives us 3 relations). By adding just one additional (fourth) asset we can get up to six synergies. Hence, a quartet is six times more synergistic, potentially, than a duet. Beyond combinations of three, the number of possible synergies will always deliver this numerical 'profit' of two. Euler (1707-83) explains this visually by referring to polygons. Here, the number of vertices denotes the number of existing 'things', or 'assets'. The number of lines that join them denotes the number of relations that may be seen as synergies.
- V represents the number of vertices
- F represents the number of faces
- E represents the number of edges
This implies that we would benefit from moving from a granular, object-defined logic of money to one that seeks to map relations in clusters that are small enough for humans to grasp, cognitively (e.g. say, four or five). The following example uses a tetrahedron as a standard figure for visualising six simultaneous relations. In practical terms, we are continuing to use this model as a template for revealing multiple synergies in which the 'intrinsic profits' are (meta)designed to serve up to six beneficiaries.
A 4-fold Relational Currency Map
A - the donor
B - the recipient
C - the transactional purpose (e.g. covenanting future support as goods and/or services)
D - the circumstances of the transaction (immediate / local / global etc.)
A 4-fold Relational Currency Map
A - the donor
B - the recipient
C - the transactional purpose (e.g. covenanting future support as goods and/or services)
D - the circumstances of the transaction (immediate / local / global etc.)
- John's talk "Monkey Business", hosted by Positive Money in March 2018
- More about the notion of relational thinking
Further Reading
Armelagos, G. J., & Cohen, M. N. (Eds.). (1984). Paleopathology at the Origins of Agriculture (pp. 235-269). Orlando (FL): Academic Press.
Arthur, B. (1996) ‘Increasing returns and the new world of business’, Harvard Business Review, July/August 1996, p. 100
Baaquie, B. E. (2018). Quantum Field Theory for Economics and Finance. Cambridge University Press.
Backwell, J., & Wood, J., (2009), “Mapping Network Consciousness: syncretizing difference to co-create a synergy-of-synergies”, in Angewandte Ascott, R.; Bast, G.; Fiel, W.; Jahrmann, M.; Schnell, R. (Eds.) New Realities: Being Syncretic, Ixth Consciousness Reframed Conference Vienna, 2008. Series: Edition.
Backwell, J., & Wood, J., (2011), ‘Catalysing Network Consciousness in Leaderless Groups: A Metadesign Tool’, in Consciousness Reframed 12, Art, Identity and the Technology of the Transformation, editors Roy Ascott & Luis Miguel Girão, University of Aveiro, Portugal, pp. 36-41
Belbin, R.M. (1996) Management teams: Why they succeed or fail. (2nd Edition published in 2003) Oxford: Butterworth-Heinemann
Bregman, R. (2017). Utopia for Realists: How We Can Build the Ideal World. Hachette UK.
Calvin, Wm., J., "The Emergence of Intelligence", in "Exploring Intelligence" (Scientific American Presents: 'Intelligence', vol. 9, no. 4, Winter 1998, New York, (ISSN 1048-0943)
Chamorro-Premuzic, T., (2017), Does Diversity Actually Increase Creativity? Harvard Business Review,
Chen, M. K,, Lakshminarayanan, V., & Santos, L. R., (2006), How Basic Are Behavioral Biases? Evidence from Capuchin Monkey Trading Behavior, Journal of Political Economy 2006 114:3, 517-537
rhesus monkeys gambling - Hot-hand bias in Rhesus monkeys Blanchard, T. C., Wilke, A., & Hayden, B. Y. (2014). Hot-hand bias in rhesus monkeys. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Animal Learning and Cognition, 40(3), 280.
macaques in gambling experiment - Strait, C. E., Blanchard, T. C., & Hayden, B. Y. (2014). Reward value comparison via mutual inhibition in ventromedial prefrontal cortex. Neuron, 82(6), 1357-1366.
Corning, P., (2003), Nature's Magic: Synergy in Evolution and the Fate of Humankind, Cambridge University Press, NY, USA, 2003
Cowan, N., (2001), The magical number 4 in short-term memory: A reconsideration of mental storage capacity, in Behavioral and Brain Sciences (2001), 24: 87-114 Cambridge University Press Copyright ©2001 Cambridge University Press doi: 10.1017/S0140525X01003922. Published online by Cambridge University Press 30 Oct 2001
Cox, G., & Dayan, Z., (2005), Cox Review of Creativity in Business: building on the UK’s strengths, TSO: Norwich, Chapter 1.
De Saussure, Ferdinand de, (1974), Course in General Linguistics, Open court Publishing, Peru, Illinoi
Deutsch, M. (2016). 83 Theory to Develop a Cooperative, Just, and Peaceful World. Scientists Making a Difference: One Hundred Eminent Behavioral and Brain Scientists Talk about Their Most Important Contributions, 395.
Dewey, J., (1939), Creative Democracy: The Task Before Us, In John Dewey and the Promise of America, Progressive Education Booklet, No. 14, American Education Press (1939)
Douthwaite, R., (1992), "The Growth Illusion", Green Books
Du Sautoy, (2009), The trillion dollar question, Guardian, 25th March 2009 http://www.theguardian.com/world/2009/mar/25/trillion-dollar-rescue-plan
Dunbar, R. I. M. (1992). "Neocortex size as a constraint on group size in primates". Journal of Human Evolution. 22 (6): 469–493. doi:10.1016/0047-2484(92)90081-J.
Easterlin, R. (1974). ‘Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence’, in Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honour of Moses Abramowitz, edited by P.A. David and M.W.Reder, Academic Press: New York and London.
Fuller, R. B., (1949) "Total Thinking", reprinted in "Ideas and Integrities: A Spontaneous Autobiographical Disclosure" (1969), Ed. Robert W. Marks, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall
Fuller, R. B., (1971), Nine Chains to the Moon, Anchor Books 1938
Fuller, R. B., (1975), “Synergetics: Explorations In The Geometry Of Thinking”, in collaboration with E.J. Applewhite. Introduction and contribution by Arthur L. Loeb. Macmillan Publishing Company, Inc., New York.
Gates, W., (1999), Business @ the Speed of Thought: Using a Digital Nervous System, with Collins Hemingway, Warner Books, NY
Graeber, D., (2001), Toward an anthropological theory of value: the false coin of our own dreams. Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 153–154. ISBN 978-0-312-24045-5
Graeber, D., (2011), Debt: The First 5000 Years, Melville
Grilli, J., Barabás, G., Michalska-Smith, M. J., & Allesina, S. (2017). Higher-order interactions stabilize dynamics in competitive network models. Nature doi:10.1038/nature23273
Guardian, Mon 25 Jun 2018 19.18 BST (https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2018/jun/25/nigel-farage-denies-shorting-value-of-sterling-on-night-of-brexit-vote (downloaded 1-07-18)
Hageman, A. (2016). When EcoMedia Gets Weird: Björk—Timothy Morton—Anthropocene. Teaching Media Quarterly, 4(3).
Hamilton, C. (2017). Defiant earth: the fate of humans in the Anthropocene. John Wiley & Sons.
Hawken, P., Lovins, A., and Lovins, H.L. (1999), Natural Capitalism, Little, Brown, and Company: New York.
Hellinger, B., & Ten Hövel, G. (1999). Acknowledging what is: conversations with Bert Hellinger. Zeig Tucker & Theisen Publishers.
Inoue, S., & Matsuzawa, T. (2007). Working memory of numerals in chimpanzees. Current Biology, 17(23), R1004-R1005.
International Air Transport Association website
Jackson, O. (2018). Confusion reigns: are cryptocurrencies commodities or securities?. International Financial Law Review.
Jackson, Tim (2009). Prosperity Without Growth: Economics for a Finite Planet. Sustainable Development Commission.
Joordens, J. C., d’Errico, F., Wesselingh, F. P., Munro, S., De Vos, J., Wallinga, J., ... & Mücher, H. J. (2015). Homo erectus at Trinil on Java used shells for tool production and engraving. Nature, 518(7538), 228.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (2013). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. In Handbook of the fundamentals of financial decision making: Part I (pp. 99-127). Chicago
Kahneman, D., Thinking, Fast & Slow, (2011). Straus and Giroux. New York.
Kauffman, S., (1995), At Home in the Universe, the search for the laws of self-organization’, Oxford University Press Inc, New York
Koestler, A., (1964). The Act of Creation, Penguin, London
Kramer, (2010), History Begins at Sumer, pp. 52–55.
Kvitash, V. I. (2003) Specific relonic patterns from non-specific or useless laboratory data, Kybernetes, Vol. 32 Iss: 5/6, pp. 607-628
Lakoff, G., & Johnson, M., (1980) Metaphors We Live By, University of Chicago: Chicago and London
Landry, C., (2000), The Creative City: A Toolkit for Urban Innovators, Earthscan Ltd, UK & USA, ISBN-10: 1853836133, ISBN-13: 978-1853836138
Layard, R., (2005), Happiness. Lessons from a New Science, Allen Lane: London.
Macquarie, R., (2018), __A GREEN BANK OF
ENGLAND, Central Banking for a Low-Carbon Economy__, a report by Positive Money presented to UK parliament on 15th May, 2018.
Margulis, L. (1998) Symbiotic Planet: A New Look at Evolution, Basic Books, New York.
Marshall, A. (2005). From Principles of Economics. In readings in 'The Economics of the Division of Labour: The Classical Tradition' (pp. 195-215).
Maturana, H. & Varela, F.,(1992). The Tree of Knowledge; biological roots of understanding. Boston: Shambala.
Varela, F., Maturana, H. & Uribe, R. (1974) "Autopoiesis: the organization of living systems, its characterization and a model". Biosystems 5, pp. 187–196.
Maturana, H., & Varela, F., (1980): ‘Autopoiesis and Cognition; the realisation of the Living’, in Boston Studies in Philosophy of Science, Reidel: Boston.
McDonough, W. & Braungart, M., (2002), Cradle to Cradle: Remaking the Way We Make Things, North Point Press: New York.
Meadows, D., (1999), ‘Leverage Points; places to intervene in a system’, The Sustainability Institute, http://www.sustainer.org/pubs/Leverage_Points.pdf, accessed 14 August, 2009.
Mészáros, I., (2006). Marx's Theory of Alienation. Merlin Press. p. 96. ISBN 978-0-85036-554-2. Retrieved 8 March 2011
Nieuwenhuijze, O, & J. Wood, (2006), ‘Synergy and Sympoiesis’, in the Writing of Joint Papers; anticipation with/in imagination, International Journal of Computing Anticipatory Systems, edited by Daniel M. Dubois, Centre for Hyperincursive Anticipation in Ordered Systems: Liège, Belgium, Volume 10, pp. 87-102.
Olins, W., (1989), Corporate identity: making business strategy visible through design, Thames & Hudson, (London)
Goleman, D., (1996), "Emotional Intelligence; why it can matter more than IQ", Bloomsbury, Great Britain
Ponting, C., (1991), "A Green History of the World", Penguin
Rapley, J., (2017). Twilight of the Money Gods: Economics as a Religion and How it all Went Wrong, Simon & Schuster
Rayner, A., (2012), NaturesScope, O Books ISBN-13: 1846949807
Reynolds, A., & Lewis, D., (2017), "Teams Solve Problems Faster When They’re More Cognitively Diverse", Harvard Business Review, March, 2017
Romer, P., M., (1986) Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth, Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 94(5), pages 1002-37, October
Ryan-Collins, J., Greenham, A., Werner, R., Jackson, A., (2011), Where Does Money Come from? A guide to the UK monetary and banking system, publisher - New Economics Foundation p. 12
Schroepfer-Walker, K., Wobber, V., Hare, B. (2015): 'Experimental evidence that grooming and play are social currency in bonobos and chimpanzees' (2015), 'Bonobo Cognition and Behaviour', pp. 299-316, DOI: 10.1163/9789004304178_014
Simmel, G., (1900), The Philosophy of Money”, Routledge; New York & London
Smith, A. (1827). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (No. 25202). Printed at the University Press for T. Nelson and P. Brown.
Sperber, D., & Wilson, D., (1986), Relevance; Communication and Cognition, Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, Mass.
Stahel, W. R. (2015), in The Circular Economy — A Wealth of Flows (ed. Webster, K.) 86–103 (Ellen MacArthur Foundation, 2015).
Stern, N. (2006). "Summary of Conclusions" (PDF). Executive summary (short). Stern Review Report on the Economics of Climate Change (pre-publication edition). HM Treasury. (see summary)
Tarnas, R., (1991), The Passion of the Western Mind, Pimlico: location?
Thackara, J. (2005) In the Bubble: Designing in a Complex World. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Urch, E. J. (1929). The Law Code of Hammurabi. ABAJ, 15, 437.
Veblen, T., (1902), The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions, New York: Macmillan.
Wahl, D. C., (2016 Designing Regenerative Cultures Axminster, UK: Triarchy Press, 2016
Wood, J. (2007), Design for Micro-utopias; thinking beyond the possible, Ashgate: UK.
Wood, J., (2012), Creativity & Biodiversity; towards a synergy-of-synergies, paper in the Journal of Advances in System Sciences & Applications, Editor, Prof. Jeffrey (Yi Lin) Forrest, An official journal of the International Institute for General Systems Studies, Vol. 12, (3), pp. 232
Wood, J., (2017), "From Products to Relations: Adding jeong to the metadesigner’s vocabulary", chapter in A Handbook of Sustainable Product Design by Jonathan Chapman, Routledge, ISBN-10: 1138910171, ISBN-13: 978-1138910171
Yunus, M., (2007), ‘Creating a World Without Poverty; social business and the future of capitalism’, Publicaffairs, USA